Mimicking the global super-rich at an anti-tax-haven demo in Trafalgar Square during May’s Global Anti-Corruption Summit.
Mimicking the global super-rich at an anti-tax-haven demo in Trafalgar Square during May’s Global Anti-Corruption Summit.
Photo: Neil Hall/Anadolu Agency/Getty Images

August this year saw one of few precious victories in the fight against the offshore economy. A European Union special commission ruled that Apple Inc has been paying an illegally low level of tax to the government of Ireland for the past 25 years, and must reimburse the state to the tune of €13 billion ($14 billion) plus interest.1 With its leaders actively trying to purge the island’s reputation as a corporate tax haven, taking the money should be a no-brainer.

Yet they are doing the opposite. Like Apple, Ireland is filing for an appeal. The rationale for this, as Finance Minister Michael Noonan explained it, is that taking the tax money owed ‘would be like eating the seed potatoes, and destroying the future for people for short-term advantage now’.2

Cute though the metaphor may be, it almost certainly has no merit in this case. Thirteen billion euros would go a long way in a small country with an unemployment rate of nearly 10 per cent.3 It could knock the national debt – currently 94 per cent of GDP – down to less than 88.4, 5

However, Noonan’s broader point is not so easily dismissed. In the short run, small countries with fragile economies do stand to gain from attracting foreign investment through low tax rates. If their governments were to unilaterally raise taxes on capital, so much might leave the country that overall tax revenues could actually decline.

So it is of little surprise that rates of taxation on corporate profits – and private wealth – have dropped steadily over the past half-century as it becomes progressively easier to move money across borders. In the 35 countries in the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), for instance, corporate tax has fallen dramatically, from an average of 30 per cent in 2000 to 23 per cent today.6 (In the early 1980s rates hovered around 50 per cent.) Transnationals benefit and our governments are poorer and more indebted.

Changing priorities

While there is a growing push to hold tax dodgers accountable, this has met with stiff resistance from entrenched interests. The resulting stalemate is precisely why existing attempts to regulate tax havens have failed. At best, the end results have been half-baked policies that rely on voluntary or on-request information sharing, rather than mandatory compliance.

To rein in the offshore bonanza two basic conditions must be met. First, financial transparency will need to improve. The offshore banking industry thrives on its ability to hide the true owners of wealth, which makes it impossible for tax authorities to know which assets to target.1

Second, future policies must establish stronger control over capital – in particular its geographical mobility. Whereas transparency is particularly vital for combating tax evasion by private individuals, capital control is more important for combating tax avoidance by corporations. By raising the cost of moving capital around the world it becomes easier to levy taxes on it.

Priorities to policies

Unilateral solutions by sovereign states may be better than nothing, but they are plagued with loopholes and problems of enforcement. The US, whose Foreign Account Taxation Compliance Act (FATCA) demands that foreign banks disclose accounts held by American citizens or face a tax of 30 per cent on income-earning assets held in the US, is probably the boldest unilateral step. It’s too soon to tell whether this 2014 policy will be effective.7 If history is any guide, its impact is likely to be limited: offshore banks can escape simply by selling significant US assets.8

Another unilateral option is capital controls – common in the post-World War Two period when regulators imposed a tax or a cap on the flow of capital across international borders.

Given that international regulatory institutions remain weak, unilateral options appear to be a good place to start. But they also have major logistical failings that allow wealth to continue slipping off the radar. Capital controls have real potential, but they are more effective when implemented within a co-operative framework.

A complete solution to the problem must then be constructed, dauntingly, at the global level. The proposals brought forward in the past three years by French economists Thomas Piketty and Gabriel Zucman seem to check all these boxes, although they are not easily accomplished.

Piketty has proposed the idea of a global tax on capital, a policy requiring all countries to co-operatively ‘establish a tax schedule applicable to all wealth around the world and then decide how to apportion the revenues’.9 In theory, this policy would diminish or even destroy the opportunities for Apple-style tax avoidance schemes.

It would also demand complete financial transparency, an issue discussed by Zucman in his book The Hidden Wealth of Nations, which focuses specifically on the offshore economy. Historically, Zucman finds that the existing half-measures have done nothing to curb tax evasion: they have been counterproductive because they increase the incentive of remaining tax havens to stay outside of the framework. ‘To be effective,’ he writes, ‘a fight against tax evasion has to be truly global.’8

Zucman proposes that the international community establish a global financial register which would record the ownership of all financial assets and enable governments to tax effectively their own citizens’ wealth.

Institutional vacuum

There is no doubt that Piketty and Zucman’s policies would go a long way toward eliminating the problem of tax havens and perhaps even tax evasion in general. The problem is that obtaining this level of international co-operation is extremely difficult. At the moment, the only two institutions with a truly global purview are not well positioned to enforce this kind of policy.

The United Nations, on the one hand, has a fairly progressive track record, but has never had a strong stake in economic policy and lacks regulatory muscle. The World Trade Organization, on the other, is far more interested in protecting capitalists’ interests than the public’s. If such proposals are to be realized, these organizations will have to be either radically transformed, or some entirely new institution will need to be created.

Then there is the OECD, which in the past two years has begun to develop an international network for tax-related information sharing. Constructed partly in response to the US’s FATCA legislation, the Common Reporting Standard will mandate participating countries to automatically share data on the ownership of wealth residing in domestic banks. While the legislation’s scope – 100 signatories, including major tax havens – is impressive, its lack of effective penalties for non-compliance leaves cause for pessimism.10

A comprehensive solution is ambitious. It must be both simple enough for easy multilateral implementation and comprehensive enough to ensure that money does not slip through the cracks between different regulatory bodies.

Whether we can construct such a system depends on governments having the political stomach for it. That depends on the amount of pressure their citizens, weary of revenue-starved austerity, can bring to bear.

Niko Block is a Toronto-based writer and activist.

  1. EU nin.tl/tax-Apple-benefits
  2. The Independent, Cian Murray, ‘Noonan: Taking €13bn in Apple taxes would be “destroying the future for short-term advantage”’, 30 August 2016
  3. Eurostat nin.tl/tables-graphs
  4. Eurostat nin.tl/gross-debt
  5. Reuters, Abhinav Ramnarayan, ‘Apple tax windfall could help ease Ireland’s debts says S&P’, 31 August 2016
  6. OECD nin.tl/oecd-outlook-st
  7. The Economist, ‘FATCA’s flaws’, 28 June 2014
  8. Gabriel Zucman, The Hidden Wealth of Nations, University of chicago Press, 2015
  9. Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-first Century, Harvard University Press, 2014
  10. OECD nin.tl/tax-info-exchange